Sunday, October 24, 2010

Microfinance ... Is it moving in a dangerous direction?

Dear Colleagues

I have been very concerned about the evolving nature of the global microfinance industry for quite a long time ... perhaps about five years. This is about the time the mainstream banking and finance sector became interested in microfinance, as they identified the possibility of profit in a new asset class.

The bankers and financial experts argued that the microfinance sector's need for capital could only be satisfied by significant access to the capital markets ... and for this, microfinance institutions needed to be profitable.

It is clear to me ... and it is the very foundation of the business model for microfinance championed by people like Muhammad Yunus, founder of the Grameen organization ... that microfinance uses money as a part of a program that aims to improve the quality of life of poor people. When the Grameen initiatives started in the 1970s ... together with BRAC and others ... the work was clearly "social" in nature and it was "sustainable" because the money being used did not simply disappear as it did in every other of the development initiatives being funded.

My own perspective was that microfinance was a palliative ... making poverty more livable, but not enough to make a difference to the community as a whole. I saw microfinance as a positive intervention, but not a sufficient intervention. I argued then, and argue today that microfinance in the Grameen mode is desirable as part of a portfolio of development interventions in a community.

I have never argued for growth of microfinance in a "for profit" mode as a desirable development intervention. For me this is an institutionalized version of the "money lender" that the Grameen model interventions sought to eliminate. I have argued for more development investment, because most communities are sadly lacking in a lot of the underlying infrastructure that would help people to progress out of poverty.

I have also argued that there needs to be better socio-economic performance metrics so that the performance of society can be tracked and the impact of various interventions seen in an objective way. Without metrics about value, the big banks and their money are going to swamp initiatives that are merely trying to get more economic benefit into the hands of poor people who are doing all they can to work themselves on to the bottom rungs of the socio-economic ladder!

The following was written by a colleague a couple of days ago ... following up on an essay he wrote for Microfinance Focus Magazine a year before!
Editorial: AP Microfinance Crisis – a signpost ignored
Saturday, October 23, 2010,

Microfinance Focus, Oct. 23, 2010 : A year ago, Microfinance Focus Senior Analyst, Daniel Rozas, published an article raising a warning flag about a developing bubble in Andhra Pradesh. Rozas wrote:

“The spark that sets off a large-scale delinquency crisis can be anything and could come at any time – a rapid drop in economic growth, a populist political movement, a religious decree, or a collections effort gone bad. One can’t control the spark, but one can control how much fuel that spark can ignite.”

That spark has now been ignited. Whether the flames can be put out quickly enough to prevent disaster is by no means assured. We hope they will be. But it is also deeply disappointing to see the sector having come to this point. After all, there was no lack of recent examples to learn from: the US financial market, Bosnia, Nicaragua, Morocco, Pakistan, Kolar, and even Andhra Pradesh back in 2007. So why are we here?

At the surface, it seems that Indian MFIs were taking steps, having formed MFIN earlier this year with the explicit objective of developing lending standards, including caps on total debt levels for clients. It sounded reasonable. But whether these actions were driven by real recognition of the risks, or simply visible motions to quell concerns raised by RBI and others, it’s apparent that they were not driven by any sense of urgency. MFIs were simply too busy to implement real changes.

SKS was too busy with its IPO. Other large NBFCs were too busy trying to catch up to SKS. Regulators were too busy worrying about profits and interest rates. Meanwhile, growth has continued unabated, including in Andhra Pradesh. Seems everyone was so preoccupied trying to win the race that they failed to see the cliff up ahead.

We are hopeful. Disaster may yet be avoided. And as soon as it is, we hope that – finally – MFIs will grow up and realize that the status quo is no longer tenable. And we hope they will seriously sit down with real regulators (as opposed to wolves disguised as state politicians) and find solutions that will finally put an end to fly-by-night operations, unconscionable collections practices, and dangerously weak lending standards. For if they fail to heed even this signpost, MFIs will deserve the fate that will undoubtedly await them next time around.
This is the year old article. Since this article was written there has been the SKS IPO and it is going to be interesting to see whether this proves to be a "last hurrah" for the hard profit wave of microfinance or is the beginning of something that ends up rather like the global sub-prime mortgage fiasco that still has a long way to go before it gets cleaned up.
Is There a Microfinance Bubble in South India?
Tuesday, November 17, 2009,
By, Daniel Rozas , Microfinance Consultant

By most standards, microfinance is a young sector, and in many countries it can be said to still be in its infancy. Yet its continuing spectacular growth, especially in India, should give one pause – every time promoters celebrate another multi-million-client threshold, I wonder – how many more such thresholds are left? How do we know when we’ve arrived?

This is not a philosophical question – normally, markets send signals. New customer demand drops. Prices fall. Margins decrease. However, credit markets are funny animals – the hopeful, exuberant part of our human nature dictates that, when presented with the opportunity, we tend to overestimate our repayment capacities and borrow beyond our means. And when we can borrow from one lender to repay another, we can stretch the cycle out even further. The market signal gets delayed, while a bubble builds – when the signal does come, it is in the form of the bubble bursting. Students of the US housing crisis can tell you – it is a most unpleasant signal to receive. I vividly remember the day in January 2007, when I first learned of the unusual delinquency patterns emerging in the US subprime market – at the time this affected only a small proportion of loans within a relatively small subsector of the mortgage market, and few thought then that this presaged a crisis that would engulf the entire mortgage market, let alone the global economy. Yet even though subprime lending had subsequently all but vanished by spring of 2007, it could not prevent the worldwide tsunami from crashing down nearly two years later. Such is the nature of bubbles.

The trouble is, determining whether we are actually in a bubble is no easy task. A look at the US stock bubble of the late 90s and the housing bubble of ’04-07 shows a familiar pattern – the eager participants are hypnotized by the glitter of their apparent success, the “wise seers” seek ways to explain visible deviations from the norm, while the few lone voices calling for a time-out are made outcasts of society. Yet when the bubble finally bursts, everyone adopts the common refrain: why didn’t “they” (the government, the corporations, the media) do something – the bubble was so obvious!

Estimating Microfinance Market Capacity

One way to determine whether there is a bubble in microfinance is to ascertain market capacity (number of potential microfinance clients), then compare that to actual penetration. However, determining capacity is hardly an obvious task. In 2006, in outlining their vision for the next ten years, Rhyne and Otero included a table with a simple ratio of borrowers/population. Back then, Bangladesh had a 9.2% penetration, and the authors suggested that that may be “an upper bound for very large national penetration of microfinance.” Here’s the same table three years later. Note that since then Bangladesh has grown over 60% in penetration, while three additional countries have either reached or breached the boundary suggested by Rhyne and Otero. But what do these numbers tell us? If 9% penetration is not the upper bound, maybe 16% is? Or perhaps 30%? To get a better idea, I created a simple model for estimating the upper bound of market capacity. This is only a crude model – a more robust version would require more detailed market data, however it still provides useful insight.

The model is presented below – it uses the same borrower/population metric as above, with additional adjustments for three factors (the full sourcing and description of the assumptions is provided in the excel file, at the end of the article# :

1) Gender – since microfinance lending is mostly to women,
2) Age – to exclude the very young and very old, and
3) Wealth/financial access level – to exclude those outside the MFI target market. The $1.50/day measure is a close equivalent of the widely used figure of 600 million poor in India.

In addition to the assumptions buried in these three components, there are two additional issues that the model doesn’t capture: first, not all potential borrowers can be actual borrowers, i.e. not everyone needs to borrow all the time; and second, multiple borrowing skews the numbers as well, since the same customer gets counted multiple times. Despite these issues, the model can serve as an indicator about what’s happening in the markets and as a tool for identifying potential bubbles.


My calculations show that Bangladesh is fairly saturated, with market penetration approaching capacity. India, on the other hand, is a much more complex picture. It’s well-known that microfinance penetration in India has an extremely uneven geographic distribution – while its largest state, Uttar Pradesh (and a number of others, mostly in the north), is relatively unserved, the southern state of Andhra Pradesh (AP) and its neighbors show a very different story. Frankly, the numbers there concern me – AP has more microfinance clients than any other country in the world except for Bangladesh; it shares the distinction as the most penetrated market in the world, on par with Bangladesh; and most disquieting, the state was already at 6% over-capacity a year ago (the table uses 2008 data). Explaining these numbers without allowing for extensive multiple borrowing is indeed a challenge.

Frankly, I think this is about the strongest evidence of a bubble one could hope to find using publicly available data. When coupled with the current repayment crisis in several districts in the neighboring state of Karnataka (which has similar penetration numbers as AP), it also becomes difficult to ignore. The most commonly used arguments against the bubble theory in south India – that the isolated districts in Karnataka represent only a slither of the microfinance market and repayment rates remain otherwise high – shows only that the bubble hasn’t yet burst, not that it doesn’t exist in the first place. Another argument that has been advanced by Vikram Akula in his letter to the editor of the Wall Street Journal is that multiple borrowing is not a cause for concern, citing as evidence the Karuna Krishnaswamy 2007 study that found multiple borrowers have equal or better repayment rates compared to their single-borrower counterparts. Since multiple borrowing is a core element of what I argue is an existing bubble, a bit of discussion on the subject is warranted.

Conducted during a period of high economic growth in India, the Krishnaswamy study found that multiple borrowers, representing 7-10% of clients in his sample, consisted primarily of highly motivated entrepreneurs seeking to raise more capital than what was offered by any one MFI. This is unsurprising – due to the nature of their cycle-based lending model, MFIs knowingly underfund their borrowers, thus assembling funds from multiple MFIs is a logical strategy that Krishnaswamy suggests is simply a replacement for the informal funding sources the individuals would have tapped otherwise. This is also consistent with the money management practices documented by Collins et. al. in Portfolios of the Poor. However, as the market heats up and multiple borrowing becomes increasingly widespread, the number of multiple borrowers grows beyond these stand-out individuals – just a few months ago on the CGAP blog, N. Srinivasan stated that 25% of borrowers in urban and peri-urban areas have 5+ loans, while 3 loans is the average for all borrowers. The immediate risk is that some of these borrowers may be falling into a debt spiral, borrowing from one MFI to repay another. However, the less immediate but greater risk is that increasingly many clients are carrying debts that leave little room for absorbing even relatively moderate economic shocks. Multiple lending on such a large scale has a minimal track-record, and the examples that exist (e.g. Bolivia in 1999) should not inspire imitation. By ignoring clients’ outstanding debts, MFIs in India and elsewhere are abandoning their responsibility for prudential lending.

What Does the Future Hold?

Let me state upfront that even if one accepts the existence of a significant microfinance bubble in South India, that doesn’t guarantee that Andhra Pradesh or any other geographic area is bound to have a crisis. However, I would argue that these areas show vastly increased sector-wide risk, and thus, significant probability of a large-scale crisis. In fact, the Krishna district in AP already had a repayment crisis in 2006, and though many attribute it to political interference, a number of voices have pointed out that politicians were tapping into existing borrower resentment towards the MFIs – after all, it’s hard to inflame a happy crowd. Moreover, among the other countries with high microfinance penetration, Bosnia and Nicaragua are already undergoing repayment crises. Given these examples, risk managers should heed carefully the community aspect of microfinance, which makes the sector so effective during normal times yet can also turn what otherwise would manifest as default spikes into en masse defaults that can engulf entire countries. The normal rules of risk management don’t apply then – of all their problems, the one US banks don’t have to deal with is heavily distressed American borrowers taking to the streets demanding cancellation of their debts.

As I had stated earlier on, it is impossible to prove that a bubble exists while one is still in it – the best one can do is point to data that suggests it may be happening. I can’t predict whether the microfinance bubble I believe exists and continues to grow in Andhra Pradesh and other south Indian states will deflate quietly or burst spectacularly. The outcome depends partly on luck and exigent circumstances, and partly on the actions of the MFIs themselves. In their pursuit of growth, many MFIs have continued to add large numbers of new customers in Andhra Pradesh and other highly saturated regions – I believe that is irresponsible. While rapid growth in the north is a commendable strategy for continuing expansion of financial access, pursuing the same in the south (with the exception of remote, still unserved areas) puts short-term gain not only above the long-term financial soundness of the sector, but, more importantly, above the long-term interests of the very poor the MFIs are seeking to serve. The spark that sets off a large-scale delinquency crisis can be anything and could come at any time – a rapid drop in economic growth, a populist political movement, a religious decree, or a collections effort gone bad. One can’t control the spark, but one can control how much fuel that spark can ignite.

With microfinance, we can’t afford to hope that there will be no spark. For when it does come, I’ll shed no tears for investor losses, nor for MFI managers’ pain – it’ll be the global unbanked poor who I fear will find themselves without financial access once again. India is no Bolivia – if the bubble bursts there, the entire global microfinance sector will find itself reeling. When the media swoop in for their favorite headline buzzwords, and the killer banes of illiquidity and capital flight seize the sector, there will be no rescue from development agencies then. Instead, one will hear the righteous indignations of politicians decrying “deceptions” and “manipulations”. And they will be right – microfinance rests on its reputation as a socially motivated industry, and when the biggest market in the sector comes crashing down from a crisis of its own making, it’ll bury that reputation and the rest of the industry with it.

***

About the Author : Daniel Rozas is a microfinance consultant based in Brussels. He worked in the US mortgage finance market for most of the past decade, including during the peak of the crisis last year. More recently he has been providing consulting for microfinance and development finance companies around the world, and has just published an in-depth study of MFI liquidations. Daniel’s background in finance spans a number of areas, including risk management, business strategy, and IT. Currently he is also associated with Microfinance Focus .

No comments:

Post a Comment